Pokaż uproszczony rekord

dc.contributor.authorDzionek-Kozłowska, Joanna
dc.date.accessioned2019-02-26T13:16:27Z
dc.date.available2019-02-26T13:16:27Z
dc.date.issued2017
dc.identifier.issn1899-2226
dc.identifier.urihttp://hdl.handle.net/11089/26883
dc.description.abstractThe homo economicus (Economic Man) concept is one of the best-known components of economic theorising frequently recognised as a part of the “hard core” of the mainstream 20th-century economics. This model gained such a high status in times of the marginal revolution, although it was coined in the 1830s by the classical economist John S. Mill. Nowadays, homo economicus is commonly perceived as a model of rational economic agent maximising utility or preferences. The article aims to show that both the Millian approach and the marginal approach were more complex than the contemporary incarnation of Economic Man. One of the key differences between the early stages in the evolution of homo oeconomicus and the modern version of it refers to the notion of rationality. Whereas it is the constitutive element of the 20th-century homo oeconomicus, the requirement of full rationality was never explicitly articulated by Mill and marginal economists. Therefore, at the early stages of its evolution, the homo economicus model would have been much more resistant to the objections formulated against it by the 20th-century critics.en_GB
dc.description.sponsorshipPublication of English-language versions of the volumes of the "Annales. Ethics in Economic Life" financed through contract no. 501/1/P-DUN/2017 from the funds of the Ministry of Science and Higher Education devoted to the promotion of scholarship.en_GB
dc.language.isoenen_GB
dc.publisherWydawnictwo Uniwersytetu Łódzkiegoen_GB
dc.relation.ispartofseriesAnnales. Ethics in Economic Life;6
dc.rightsThis work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 License.en_GB
dc.rights.urihttp://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0en_GB
dc.subjecthomo economicusen_GB
dc.subjectEconomic Manen_GB
dc.subjectrationalityen_GB
dc.subjectmarginal economicsen_GB
dc.subjectJohn Stuart Millen_GB
dc.subjectAlfred Marshallen_GB
dc.titleThe early stages in the evolution of Economic Man. Millian and marginal approachesen_GB
dc.typeArticleen_GB
dc.page.number33-51
dc.contributor.authorAffiliationUniversity of Lodz, Faculty of Economics and Sociology, Department of the History of Economic Thought and Economic History
dc.identifier.eissn2353-4869
dc.referencesAlter, M. (1982). Carl Menger and Homo Oeconomicus: some thoughts on Austrian theory and methodology. Journal of Economic Issues, 16(1), 149–160.en_GB
dc.referencesBecker, G. S. (1976). The economic approach to human behavior. Chicago, London: University of Chicago Press.en_GB
dc.referencesDzionek-Kozłowska, J. (2007). System ekonomiczno-społeczny Alfreda Marshalla [Socioeconomic system of Alfred Marshall]. Warsaw: Polish Scientific Publishers.en_GB
dc.referencesDzionek-Kozłowska, J., & Matera, R. (2015). Ethics in economic thought. Selected issues and various perspectives. Łódź-Kraków: Lodz University Press & Jagiellonian University Press.en_GB
dc.referencesFontaine, Ph. (1998). Menger, Jevons, and Walras un-homogenized, de-homogenized, and homogenized: A comment on Peart. American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 57(3), 333–339.en_GB
dc.referencesGiegerenzer, G. (2008). Rationality for mortals. How people cope with uncertainty. New York: Oxford University Press.en_GB
dc.referencesGiocoli, N. (2005). Modeling rational agents: The consistency view of rationality and the changing image of neoclassical economics. Cahiers d’Économie Politique, 49(2), 177–208.en_GB
dc.referencesGodłów-Legiędź, J. (1992). Doktryna społeczno-ekonomiczna Friedricha von Hayeka. Warsaw: Polish Scientific Publishers.en_GB
dc.referencesHausman, D. (2013). Philosophy of Economics. In E. N. Zalta (Ed.), The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy, Winter 2013 Edition. https://plato.stan-ford.edu/archives/win2013/entries/economics/en_GB
dc.referencesvon Hayek, F. A. (1945). The use of knowledge in society. American Economic Review, 35, 519–530.en_GB
dc.referencesvon Hayek, F. A. (1988). The fatal conceit. The errors of socialism. London, New York: Routledge.en_GB
dc.referencesHébert, R. F. (1998). Jevons and Menger re-homogenized: Who is the real “Odd Man Out?” A comment on Peart. American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 57(3), 327–332.en_GB
dc.referencesJaffé, W. (1976). Menger, Jevons and Walras de-homogenized. Economic Inquiry, 14, 511–524. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1465-7295.1976.tb00439.xen_GB
dc.referencesJevons, W. S. (1866/1965). Brief account of a general mathematical theory of Political Economy. In The theory of Political Economy, 303–314. New York: Augustus M. Kelley [originally published in Journal of the Statistical Society of London, 29].en_GB
dc.referencesJevons, W. S. (1874). Principles of science: A treatise on logic and scientific method. New York: Macmillan.en_GB
dc.referencesJevons, W. S. (1965). The theory of Political Economy. New York: Augustus M. Kelley.en_GB
dc.referencesKahneman, D. (2003). Maps of bounded rationality: Psychology for behavioral economics. American Economic Review, 93(5), 1449–1475.en_GB
dc.referencesKahneman, D. (2011). Thinking, fast and slow. New York: Farrar, Straus and Giroux.en_GB
dc.referencesKnight, F. H. (1921/1964). Risk, uncertainty and profit. New York: Augustus M. Kelley.en_GB
dc.referencesKostro, K. (2001). Hayek kontra socjalizm. Debata socjalistyczna a rozwój teorii społeczno-ekonomicznych Friedricha Augusta von Hayeka. Warszawa: Wydawnictwo DiG.en_GB
dc.referencesLazear, E. (2000). Economic Imperialism. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115(1), 99–146.en_GB
dc.referencesMäki, U. (2004). Theoretical isolation and explanatory progress: Transaction cost economics and the dynamics of dispute. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 28(3), 319–346.en_GB
dc.referencesMarshall, A. (1879/1930). The pure theory of domestic values. London: London School of Economics and Political Sciences.en_GB
dc.referencesMarshall, A. (1896/1897). The old generation of economists and the new. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 11, 115–135.en_GB
dc.referencesMarshall, A. (1907). The social possibilities of economic chivalry. Economic Journal, 17, 7–29.en_GB
dc.referencesMarshall, A. (1920). Principles of economics. London: Macmillan. Library of Economics and Liberty. http://www.econlib.org/library/Marshall/marP.htmlen_GB
dc.referencesMarshall, A. (1925). The present position of Political Economy. In A. C. Pigou (Ed.), Memorials of Alfred Marshall. London: Macmillan.en_GB
dc.referencesMarshall, A. (1996). Letter to J.N. Keynes, 17.IX.1898. In J. K. Whitaker (Ed.), The Correspondence of Alfred Marshall, Economist (Vol. 1). Cambridge, New York, Melbourne: Cambridge University Press.en_GB
dc.referencesMenger, C. (1985). Investigations into the method of social sciences with special reference to Economics. New York, London: New York University Press.en_GB
dc.referencesMenger, C. (2007). Principles of economics. Auburn: Ludwig von Mises Institute.en_GB
dc.referencesMill, J. S. (1836/1967). On the definition of Political Economy; and on the method of investigation proper to it. In J. M. Robson (Ed.), Collected works of John Stuart Mill (Vol. 4, pp. 309–339). London: University of Toronto Press, Routledge & Kegan Paul.en_GB
dc.referencesMill, J. S. (1844/1974). A system of logic ratiocinative and inductive. In J. M. Robson (Ed.), Collected works of John Stuart Mill (Vol. 7–8). London: University of Toronto Press, Routledge & Kegan Paul.en_GB
dc.referencesMill, J. S. (1873/1981). Authobiography. In J. M. Robson & J. Stillinger (Eds.), Collected works of John Stuart Mill (Vol. 1). London: University of Toronto Press, Routledge & Kegan Paul.en_GB
dc.referencesMill, J. S. (1965). Principles of Political Economy with some of their applications to social philosophy. In J. M. Robson (Ed.), Collected works of John Stuart Mill (Vol. 3). London: University of Toronto Press, Routledge & Kegan Paul.en_GB
dc.referencesMorgan, M. S. (2006). Economic Man as model man: Ideal types, idealization and caricatures. Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 28(1), 1–27.en_GB
dc.referencesNorth, D. C. (1990). Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge University Press.en_GB
dc.referencesPeart, S. J. (1998). Jevons and Menger re-homogenized?: Jaffé after 20 years. American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 57(3), 307–325.en_GB
dc.referencesSenior, N. W. (1836/1965). An outline of the science of political economy. New York: Augustus M. Kelley.en_GB
dc.referencesSimon, H. A. (1955). A behavioral model of rational choice. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 69(1), 99–118.en_GB
dc.referencesSimon, H. A. (1956). Rational choice and the structure of the environment. Psychological Review, 63(2), 129–138.en_GB
dc.referencesSzarzec, K. (2005). Racjonalny podmiot gospodarczy w klasycznej myśli ekonomicznej i jej współczesnych kontynuacjach. Warszawa: Fundacja Promocji i Akredytacji Kierunków Ekonomicznych, Polskie Towarzystwo Ekonomiczne.en_GB
dc.referencesSzarzec, K. (2006). J.S. Milla model homo oeconomicus. Przegląd Filozoficzny, 60(4), 241–256.en_GB
dc.referencesThaler, R. H., & Sunstein, C. R. (2008). Nudge: Improving decisions about health, wealth, and happiness. New Haven: Yale University Press.en_GB
dc.referencesVeblen, T. B. (1900/1919). The preconceptions of economic science: III. In The place of science in modern society and other essays (pp. 170–179). New York: B.W. Huebsch [originally published in Quarterly Journal of Economics, 14, 240–269].en_GB
dc.referencesWalras, L. (2014). Elements of theoretical economics or the theory of social wealth, 3rd Edition, (D. A. Walker & J. van Daal, Eds.). Cambridge University Press.en_GB
dc.contributor.authorEmailjoanna.dzionek@uni.lodz.pl
dc.identifier.doi10.18778/1899-2226.20.6.03
dc.relation.volume20en_GB
dc.subject.jelB12
dc.subject.jelB13
dc.subject.jelB41


Pliki tej pozycji

Thumbnail

Pozycja umieszczona jest w następujących kolekcjach

Pokaż uproszczony rekord

This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 License.
Poza zaznaczonymi wyjątkami, licencja tej pozycji opisana jest jako This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 License.