dc.contributor.author | Woźniak, Michał Gabriel | |
dc.date.accessioned | 2019-02-14T08:32:02Z | |
dc.date.available | 2019-02-14T08:32:02Z | |
dc.date.issued | 2017 | |
dc.identifier.issn | 1899-2226 | |
dc.identifier.uri | http://hdl.handle.net/11089/26808 | |
dc.description.abstract | Global capitalism is both an outcome and a stimulant of spreading not only the same market economy standards and lifestyles but moral relativism as well. Its origin goes back to Anglo-Saxon liberalism that limits the individuals to maximize their personal benefits that are measured according to the market values. The perception of human nature adopted in this ideology determines solutions as for how to achieve individual and communitarian goals and meet criteria of their validation. As a result, the development of human capital understood as the knowledge necessary to act, is focused on its subjective functions. Thus, human capital plays a more important role in the multiplication of individual benefit than in the improvement of the value of human life. Such developed human capital results in growing disparities in the knowledge assets enabling the harmonization of personal benefit with the responsibility for the valuable life of present and future generations. These disparities lead to an increase in risk of global threats to humanity. The reaction to these threats cannot be based on the development of globalization. The concept that respects the multi-faceted nature of a human being seems to be an appropriate alternative. Due to these efforts, new economics might be developed that may provide applicable educational and institutional tools for long-term sustained economic development and improve the quality of life of an individual. | en_GB |
dc.description.sponsorship | Publication of English-language versions of the volumes of the “Annales. Ethics in Economic Life” financed through contract no. 501/1/P-DUN/2017 from the funds of the Ministry of Science and Higher Education devoted to the promotion of scholarship. | en_GB |
dc.language.iso | en | en_GB |
dc.publisher | Wydawnictwo Uniwersytetu Łódzkiego | en_GB |
dc.relation.ispartofseries | Annales. Ethics in Economic Life;5 | |
dc.rights | This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-NoDerivatives 4.0 License. | en_GB |
dc.rights.uri | http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0 | en_GB |
dc.subject | economic growth and development | en_GB |
dc.subject | business ethics | en_GB |
dc.title | Human capital and economic development: The axiological perspective | en_GB |
dc.type | Article | en_GB |
dc.page.number | 83-93 | |
dc.contributor.authorAffiliation | University of Rzeszow, Faculty of Economics, Department of Economics | |
dc.identifier.eissn | 2353-4869 | |
dc.references | Azariadis C., & Drazen, A. (1990). Threshold externalities in economic development. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 105(2), 501–526. | en_GB |
dc.references | von Bertalanffy, L. (1984). Ogólna teoria systemów. Warszawa: Państwowe Wydawnictwo Naukowe. | en_GB |
dc.references | Castells, M. (1986). High technology, word development and the structural transformation: The trends and debate. Alternatives, 11, 297–342. | en_GB |
dc.references | Choosing to grow: Knowledge, innovation and jobs in a cohesive society. Report to the Spring European Council, 21 March 2003 on the Lisbon strategy of economic, social and environmental renewal. (2003). COM (2003) 5 final. [EU Commission – COMDocument] | en_GB |
dc.references | Czerny, M. (2005). Globalizacja a rozwój. Wybrane zagadnienia geografii społeczno-gospodarczej świata. Warszawa: Wydawnictwo Naukowe PWN. | en_GB |
dc.references | Domański, R. (1993). Kapitał ludzki i wzrost gospodarczy. Warszawa: Wydawnictwo Naukowe PWN. | en_GB |
dc.references | Horx, M. (2002). Die acht Sphären der Zukunft. Wien–München: Signum. | en_GB |
dc.references | Kozielecki, J. (1980). Koncepcje psychologiczne człowieka. Warszawa: Państwowy Instytut Wydawniczy. | en_GB |
dc.references | Krueger, O. A. (1974). The political economy of the rent-seeking society. American Economic Review, 64(3), 291–303. | en_GB |
dc.references | Lambert, T. (1999). Problemy zarządzania. Warszawa: ABC. | en_GB |
dc.references | Lewis, W. W. (2005). Potęga wydajności. Warszawa: CeDeWu. | en_GB |
dc.references | Lucas, R. E. (1988). On the mechanics of economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics, 22(1), 3–42. | en_GB |
dc.references | Nowak, L. (1991). U podstaw teorii socjalizmu. Dynamika władzy. Poznań: Wydawnictwo Nakom. | en_GB |
dc.references | Piasecki, R. (2003). Rozwój gospodarczy a globalizacja. Warszawa: Wydawnictwo Naukowe PWN. | en_GB |
dc.references | Romer, P. (1986). Increasing Returns and Long – Run Growth. Journal of Political Economy, 94, 1002–1037. | en_GB |
dc.references | Strategia lizbońska. Droga do sukcesu zjednoczonej Europy. (2002). Warszawa: Urząd Komitetu Integracji Europejskiej. | en_GB |
dc.references | Tullock, G. (1967). The welfare costs of tariffs, monopolies, and theft. Western Economic Journal, 5(3), 224–232. | en_GB |
dc.references | Williamson, O. E. (1998). Ekonomiczne instytucje kapitalizmu. Warszawa: Wydawnictwo Naukowe PWN. | en_GB |
dc.references | Woźniak, M. G. (2005a). Czy religia może być jednym ze źródeł kapitału intelektualnego. In S. Partycki (Ed.), Religia i gospodarka. Lublin: Wydawnictwo KUL. | en_GB |
dc.references | Woźniak, M. G. (2005b). Kapitał ludzki i intelektualny jako czynnik wzrostu gospodarczego i ograniczania nierówności społecznych [badania statutowe nr 21/KES/1/2005/S/213], part II. Kraków: Akademia Ekonomiczna w Krakowie.[unpublished manuscript] | en_GB |
dc.references | Woźniak, M. G. (2007). Kapitał ludzki w rozwoju gospodarczym w perspektywie aksjologicznej. Annales. Ethics in Economic Life, 10(1), 189–197. | en_GB |
dc.contributor.authorEmail | wozniakg@uek.krakow.pl | |
dc.identifier.doi | 10.18778/1899-2226.20.5.07 | |
dc.relation.volume | 20 | en_GB |
dc.subject.jel | A13 | |
dc.subject.jel | M14 | |
dc.subject.jel | O15 | |